|
|
What
Really Happened to the USA Savings
and Loan Industry
By Jonathan
Larson
The death of the
Savings and Loan industry caused the typical assortment of finger-pointing,
official hearings, investigations, and other irrelevant motion usually
seen in Washington whenever genuine political anger is felt from beyond
the beltway.
In Houston, an investigative journalist thought he found a Mafia or C.I.A.
connection to the S & L crises.
But searching for 'the bad guys' is not going to shed much light on the problem
nor return but a tiny fraction of the money involved. In fact, looking for
a few 'criminals' may be leading us away from the real problems.
The 'bailout' of the S & L is still estimated at $500 billion. It defies
belief that the C.I.A., the organization that brought us the Bay of Pigs invasion,
could organize such a grand theft. The Mafia could never have infiltrated that
many organizations. In spite of the stories of the private jets and artwork
associated with some of the more notorious S & L failures, bizjets and
artwork are not expensive enough to bring down that many institutions nor cost
more than the Vietnam war.
And no matter how much fun it was to watch Neil Bush squirm, the S & L
tragedy is certainly beyond the scope of the totality of 80's pinhead yuppies.
Above the clamor for blood there is the occasional voice heard that the directors
of the failed S & L's may not only be innocent, but in fact victims. If
they are, all evidence seems to indicate that they are yet another of the victims
of the high interest rates associated with the war on inflation. For only long-term
public policy could cause such a mess.
Inflation is most commonly defined as too much money chasing too few goods.
This problem can occur irrespective money's form. When Spain was flooded with
silver and gold from the Americas in the 16th century, they had inflation.
People sometimes believe that now that money is information in a core memory
unit of a computer or encoded on the back of a piece of plastic, inflation
has become a more persistant problem. They are probably correct even though
there is little casual relationship.
In fact, inflation exists largely because there are several types and causes.
Because of this, adjustments in monetary policy and high interest rates, the
only methods of flighting inflation in the 1980's, are something like wide-spectrum
pesticides that do not kill all the pests and wind up killing songbirds and
other things we want to save. A look at the main inflation types will reveal
why this is so.
#1) Inflation in the price of real property. Nothing acts more like the standard
economic model of money chasing goods than land. Except for some heroic but
otherwise insignificant efforts by the Dutch, the amount of land on the planet
has remained constant for a very long time. Increase the supply of money and
the price of real estate will rise. Decrease the supply and the price will
fall.
But even this most simple form of inflation has complications. Not all land
is equally attractive and most of the really interesting land has buildings
on it. Pure farmland responded to the 1979 monetary cure for inflation almost
immediately. By 1982, speculation in farmland had ended and the price of land
had returned to something resembling the value of the crops that could be produced
thereon. But land with buildings, or even land that could be built on, was
subjected to the more sophisticated inflations.
#2) Commodity inflation (with a bow to Barry Commoner) is a more complex form
that showed itself in the 70's. The law of non-renewable resources states that
every barrel of oil (scoop of ore, etc.) extracted from the earth make the
next barrel more expensive to find and extract. The easy to find oil was found
first. The first oil well was less than 200 feet deep and was found in Pennsylvania
on dry land. Now oil is extracted from extremely inhospitable places like the
North Sea with wells thousands of feet deep.
Although commodity inflation applies to any natural material desired by the
industrial state, oil was special for two main reasons; a) oil is burned and
so is destroyed in any meaningful sense, and b) oil is virtually irreplaceable.
Almost all American cities were designed around the automobile. To do without
oil is unthinkable.
With people willing to pay any price for oil because their survival was at
stake, higher oil prices of the 70's drove all other forms of inflation as
people strove to keep up with the price rise of this basic necessity to their
lives.
Commodity inflation was so persistant that none of the milder attempts to combat
this form of inflation in the 70's was even partially successful. The stringent
monetary policy of Volker only worked against oil prices over a much longer
period of time. Mexico, then Venezuala, Nigeria and so on began to produce
more oil as their economies sank deeper into interest-driven debt. Iran got
into a war with Iraq which meant they had to cheat on their production quotas.
By 1983, the power of OPEC to raise oil prices at will had been broken.
Some ground was also gained on the demand side of the equation. While Americans
still needed their daily fix of petroleum supplies in order to live, technological
changes such as more fuel-efficient cars allowed them to live on somewhat less.
Disorganization in OPEC combined with a reduced demand kept oil prices essentially
steady throughout the 80's. However, because of its special nature, commodity
inflation as it applies to oil will certainly return with a vengence.
But inflation can still persist because of the most complex form:
#3) Market or producer inflation (with a bow to John Kenneth Galbraith.) Land
nor commodities are very interesting except what people do with them. What
humans do to natural resources gives them their value. The silicon in sand
has far less value than the silicon in a computer chip. The whole goal of industrial
enterprise is to add highly specialized value to natural resources. Those that
are successful form industrial monopolies based on expertise, tooling, and
other capital. Industrial monopolies are not the absolute monopolies referred
to in economics textbooks or cursed by the 'Trustbusters.'
Industrial monoplies are similar to the output of a great chef. Many can prepare
food, some can do it so well, they can command a premium price. Most of the
very profitable products of the 20th century are based on secret, patented,
forms of expertise using very expensive 'untinsels.' Mercedes Benz, for example,
has a highly successful industrial recipe. Mercedes-Benz does not have a monopoly
on the construction of transportation devices nor even of automobiles and trucks
but if a person wants a Mercedes, he or she has to buy from Mercedes.
But everyone who makes things struggles to have a unique and equally successful
recipe. The reasons are simple. 1) If a person or company has an industrial
monopoly, they can raise prices in spite of efforts to hold down price increases.
2) Manufactured goods have minimum prices. Many costs of manufacture are built
into the basic ability to make things. These fixed, enabling, capital costs
mean that even if a manufacturer would want to lower prices, he or she cannot.
Instead, the only alternative in many cases to raising or stable prices is
to cease production.
Ironically, the enforcement element of monetarism, high interest rates, raises
the fixed costs of production and means that anyone who can raise prices, will
do so because the alternative of bankruptcy is so grim.
Even by 1990 when the fight against inflation had been waged for 11 years and
had been highly successful against higher land and commodity prices, medicine
costs continued to escalate because both doctors and medical equipment manufacturers
seem to be uncovering new and unique products and processes that can be defined
as industrial monopolies.
Given the varied forms of inflation, the nature of S & L's, and the weapon
of high interst rates used to fight inflation, the S & L tragedy was almost
inevitable.
S & L's had a wonderful mission--to provide low cost mortgages for home
ownership. This they did very well. Low-cost home ownership in the 50's and
60's created and defined the enlarging American middle class. Because of the
S & L mission, capital reserve requirements and supervision was minimal.
The last thing on which a member of the American middle class was going to
default was his or her home. These were the safest investments imaginable.
But the basic S & L flaw was that while the investments were in long-term
mortgages, the deposits were in short-term instruments. This was never much
of a problem until interest rates went from 8% in 1978 to 20+% in 1980 and
no one with an 8% (or 7.5% or 5%) rushed out to have his mortgage raised to
20%.
The S & L's screamed for help. Congress threw them the 'lifeline' of deregulation.
The S & L's were forced by economic circumstance from their safe cozy world
of financing the nests of America's middle-class into the high-risk world of
high-interest lending.
And what a crazy world it turned out to be. There are precious few legitimate
investments that return 20+% or even the 10-12% that S & L's sought as
the decade of the 80's continued. Their traditional line of business--homes--had
never been an investment but rather a consumer product. This continued to be
true even though raising prices for housing due to the heavy influx of the
'baby boom' into market caused many to treat housing as an investment. Related
fields such as real estate development and energy exploration were coming under
the control of monetary policy and were losing their ability to return at high
rates.
This did not leave the loan officers at the S & L's with much to choose
from. Real industrial monopolies such as new and patented medicines were beyond
their reach and attempts at such monopolies in the real estate world such as
high-priced vacation condos and downtown office space proved futile as everyone
in the business chose to finance the same sort of development.
Even in the realm of traditional lending by S & L's--building--the concept
of the industrial monopoly was essentially beyond the average expertise of
the typical loan committee. Homes, while harder to produce than a hamburger,
are still fairly simple products. Homes are assembled from prefabricated components
such as windows, plywood, nails, carpet, doors, etc. using tools that are mass-produced,
cheap, and available anywhere.
Anyone with money, reasonable care, and the ability to organize strenuous physical
work can build homes. Many people build their own quite successfully. The difference
between the builder of a few homes a year out of the back of his truck and
one who builds hundreds is mostly determined by an access to capital.
Even skyscrapers are assembled from prefabricated parts and while much more
difficult to build than a house, are well within the reach of many builders.
Imagine the scene of the typical S & L in 1983. They have been told that
their investment must return a higher rate. They already know that unimproved
land is no longer appreciating in value but is actually falling. Middle-class
homebuilding has all but collapsed in the recession of 81-82.
The search begins for projects which have a higher value built into the structure.
The notion of the industrial recipe applies in some degree to homebuilding.
Higher priced housing is more profitable because it contains unique features
that are the product of specialized skills. Only upper-priced housing sold
during the recession of 81-82 because only the rich who were essentially unaffected
by the recession were able or fearless enough to buy.
Suddenly, in every loan committee, a similar kind of decision was reached.
High-priced housing with plenty of features became the appropriate form of
housing to fund. Within months, there was a glut of expensive housing.
The principle was also applied to expensive vacation destinations and commercial
real estate. Charles Keating of Lincoln Federal Savings and Loan is an example
of a builder who actually took over an S & L for the purposes of funded
his own pet projects. He built a hotel in Arizona with the most specialized
skills employed. There are probably more guilded ceilings in Keating's hotel
than in the Palace of Versailles. And while Keating employed an army of craftsmen,
his hotel would have to charge $300/night and would have to be 90% occupied
to pay the bills.
Therin lies a supreme irony. Those areas of the country which were considered
properous were those same areas of the 'go-go' S & L's. Obviously, free
lending policies are good for the economy. But the distortions imposed by high-interest
rates caused the kind of building guarenteed to fail if enough people did it
at the same time. The rich are rich by definition because there are few of
them. Selling to them returns high profits only if done by an exclusive few
producers.
The death of the S & L industry was only one of the serious problems associated
with the crazy rates of interest that have troubled the world's economies since
1979. It may not even be the most serious. But $500 billion is still a lot
of money for which most Americans could have thought of better uses.
SEE
ALSO: MONEY!
RETURN
TO: VEBLEN FOR THE NEW MILLENNIUM
RETURN
TO: Correcting the history of Thorstein Veblen |